ICTs, Globalization, and the Rise of Right-Wing Populism in the West: A Complex Systems Analysis
“Systems often display non-linear relationships, outcomes cannot be understood by the adding together of units or their relations, and many of the results of actions are unintended. Complexities can appear in even what would seem to be simple and deterministic situations.”
-Robert Jervis, “Systems Effects: Complexity in Political and Social Life”
“All major social changes are ultimately characterized by a transformation of space and time in the human experience.”
-Manuel Castells, “The Rise of the Network Society”
" ‘Do you think me a learned, well-read man?’
‘Certainly,’ replied Zi-gong. ‘Aren't you?’
‘Not at all,‘ said Confucius. ‘I have simply grasped one thread which links up the rest.’ “
-Sima Qian
When millions of Americans woke up the morning of November 9, 2016 to learn that Donald J. Trump, businessman and former reality-show star, had been elected President of the United States, there was, among large segments of the populace, a collective sense of shock. For many, it was unthinkable the brash, politically-inexperienced candidate could ascend to the highest office in the country and arguably the most powerful position in the world. But, without diagnosing all of the specific conditions that led to his win and Hillary Clinton’s defeat—and there are, of course, many—it is possible to recognize Trump’s success in the context of a wider trend happening throughout the Western world.
Every generation likes to think of itself as being of particular historical importance, or of experiencing uniquely groundbreaking change and development. But it would not be inaccurate to say that the transformations our society is currently undertaking in terms of technological growth and globalization are unprecedented. The advent of information and communications technologies (ICTs) has eliminated barriers to international communication and exchange, fueling the rise of a globalized economy and political system. This new globally-interdependent system, as well as the ICTs that both enabled its spread and that arose from its existence, are changing the nature of labor and work, and in turn fundamental social conditions. Such rapid change has had incredible economic and social implications, in turn sparking subsequent political reactions. In particular, the West has seen an emergence of populist, nativist, protectionist, and anti-globalist movements, notably among right-wing factions.
In Western countries, this globalized economy and increased innovation has facilitated the loss of manufacturing jobs, the outsourcing of jobs to developing countries, the automation of jobs, a change in types of jobs available, the hollowing-out of the middle class, the rise of immigration (particularly from non-Western nations), and fundamental changes to society’s value systems and cultural capital. These trends are not necessarily particularly new—with every technological innovation comes the death of certain industries and significant cultural change, and society adapts—but the speed at which these changes are occurring may have serious implications. Applying principles of complex systems theory to the international system, we see that the trend of emerging ICTs can have far-reaching and unintended consequences. By changing the nature of labor, including where and what kinds of jobs are available, and by altering existing cultural and social relations, ICTs have facilitated a political backlash in the form of right-wing populist (RWP) movements around the world, and particularly in the West. Placed within the complex system that is international relations, these political trends have the capacity to seriously alter the global political order. For the sake of scope, this paper only examines RWP movements in Western countries, though RWP has also established footholds in the political mainstream of other democratic countries like India, Japan, Turkey, and Russia (“Western” being narrowly defined).
I. Complex Systems
To understand how the international system fits into a complex systems framework, it’s important to first lay the foundation for what complex systems theory actually is. On the most basic level, complex systems theory, also known as complexity theory, is an emerging approach to thinking about how systems work that emphasizes the importance of the interactions between many different variables, typically in non-linear fashions. Complexity theory arose out of the study of the natural world—physics and biology in particular—but has recently been adapted to the social sciences to understand how convoluted systems with many actors produce particular outcomes. According to Emilian Kavalski (2007), an expert on complex systems, “…complex systems are identified by the multitude of their components, and the numerous interconnections among the subsystems of a complex system” (438).
When analyzing complex systems, it is not individual actors or even “sub-systems” (smaller collections of actors within the whole) that are the most important units of analysis, but the interactions and relationships between them. On a fundamental level, there are four major features of a complex system: first, they exhibit self-organization, meaning order emerges from the interactions between localized parts of the overall system, not an external agent. Second, they are non-linear, meaning we cannot use simple cause-and-effect models to explain events that arise from them. Third, they are open, which means they fluctuate between order and chaos in order to strike the right balance between the two. And fourth, they can co-evolve, meaning that the system and its various parts are constantly adapting and changing depending on other changes in the environment (Glover 2016).
So how does the international political system fit into this conception of complex systems theory? For starters, the global system self-organizes, evidenced by the economic sub-systems that have arisen from the interactions between actors across the world and their effects on commodity prices, stock markets, and other financial indicators. This is not to say that all actors have equal power in the meta-system, but that there is no singular external pressure pushing all actors in the same direction. The system is also non-linear, demonstrated by Edward Lorenz as the “butterfly effect”—not all actions necessarily have obvious or proportional consequences (Lorenz 1963). For example, when Mohammed Bouazizi set himself on fire in 2010 to protest the Tunisian government, his action sparked a series of protests throughout the Arab world—but chances are another person self-immolating at a different time and place would not have the same widespread effects. According to this principle, small events can have enormous consequences, large events can have minimal consequences, and the same action can have vastly different consequences depending on its context (Glover 2016).
In contrast to much of IR theory, complexity theory rejects the idea that states of equilibrium or regularity can genuinely be achieved for any significant amount of time. Instead, the international system is seen as vulnerable and fallible—alliances change, multi-lateral organizations stumble, and nations go to war. Finally, the international system co-evolves in the sense that its many composite parts are not rigid in their function or trajectory, but constantly change. The most obvious, striking example of this is when countries engage in an arms race—one country builds up arms, which triggers another country to build up its own arms for potential defense, and so on in a feedback loop (Glover 2016). Overall, the international system exhibits the characteristics of other complex systems, and can therefore be understood through a complex systems analysis framework.
II. Emerging ICTs and the New Economy
When a particular set of interactions within a complex system form a pattern, the trend can have widespread political implications. The rapid emergence of ICTs is one such trend, exerting significant influence over social, political, and economic factors, and which can have far-reaching consequences across the complex global system. Over the past few decades, government investment in science and technology has led to an acceleration in innovation, including ICTs that greatly reduced the cost of communicating across distance and time. Professor Charles Weiss identified four mechanisms through which ICTs exert influence on the global system: by changing the architecture of the overall system, including its structure, relations, and organizing principles; by changing the system’s operating procedures, including how it conducts war, diplomacy, administration, commerce, finance, and communications; by creating new issue areas and constraints on action; and changing security perceptions (Malik 2012).
With the collapse of communism around the world and the opening up of markets, we’ve seen trade, investment, and business spread throughout the world, bolstered by these new technologies. Most importantly, the birth of the Internet provided the ultimate link between people around the world, improving network computing, integrating markets, and opening channels of cultural exchange. These technologies also increased labor productivity in the United States, improving output per hour worked growth from 1.4% per year before 1995 to 2.5% between 1995-2000 (Pohjola 2002, 135).
This emerging sub-system has been called by many names: a “post-industrial society,” “Network Economy,” “Innovation Economy,” “Digital Economy,” “Information Economy,” and “Knowledge Economy.” All of these are true in a sense, and can be used interchangeably, but each only captures a specific element of this emergent system. A more encompassing term for the collective system is the “New Economy” (Pohjola 2002, 134). Walter W. Powell and Kaisa Snellman (2004), in describing the Knowledge Economy, define this system as having “production and services based on knowledge-intensive activities that contribute to an accelerated pace of technical and scientific advance, as well as rapid obsolescence,” with “a greater reliance on intellectual capabilities than on physical inputs or natural resources” (201). Put more simply by Richard Freeman (2002), the New Economy is “broadly defined by the extension of information and communication technologies…particularly the Internet, to economic activity” (1). As ICTs lowered barriers to communication, and as ICT prices dropped due to improved production, a greater share of people entered global markets, social movements and communities, and political processes—even if these new capabilities were not evenly spread throughout the world or within countries (Pohjola 2002, 139).
These new technologies also enabled an even more rapid process of globalization. With high-speed transactions, computational technologies that apply mathematical models to financial products, electronic trading, more precise tools for standardization and customization of products, the ability for flexible production, and easier coordination and logistics practices, firms were opened up to, quite literally, a whole new world of markets for both products and labor. This is not to say that such a process was an inevitable result of the forward march of ICTs—in fact, the rise of these innovations was paired with a conscious effort on the part of Western governments and institutions to de-regulate, privatize, and liberalize trade and investment (Castells 2009). As capital could easily be moved around the world, the centers of production shifted from the more-developed (and higher-cost) West to less-developed (and therefore cheaper) East Asia (Short 2016). The ensuing globalized economy, with its many interdependent nodes, became an emergent sub-system, making it extremely costly for any specific node to leave the web, as it would lose out on internal flows of capital. In this way, we can see how ICTs were a necessary factor in the process of globalization, and how the ICTs that result from and constitute globalization play a role in maintaining the system.
When a society experiences changes to the way it produces capital and value, how its people communicate with one another, and how it interacts with other societies, there are bound to be significant transformations to the way it is organized as well. In “The Wealth of Networks,” Yochai Benkler (2007) identified two important shifts now underway in modern advanced economies: a shift to an economy based on information (software, finances, accounting, innovation) and cultural production (movies, music), as well as a deluge of communication (resulting from cheaper ICTs, the most important being the Internet). According to Benkler, the convergence of these two trends leads to a greater role for decentralized, non-market social production and exchange in the economy, challenging property- and market-based forms of production. As the economic structure of society changes, favoring social capital and free exchange, social relations will adapt as well, transforming from an industrial production model to a network-based model. We can already see this transformation beginning, emboldened by ICTs, as people start getting their news from social media and their information from Wikipedia, start-ups crowdsource investments from Kickstarter and other web-based applications, and services like transportation and housing are outsourced to the “sharing” economy (Uber and Airbnb, respectively). Some of the traditional barriers to entry in the economy may have been lowered, but the shift to network-based chains of value means that those outside of these networks find themselves of increasingly less value in the market.
III. The New Economy and its Discontents
It can be easy, particularly if you are a beneficiary of these emerging trends, to take the long-view of such phenomena without considering the very real consequences. If the information revolution has accelerated shifts towards an international system characterized by increased transparency and volatility, it is clear these emerging trends in labor and social relations present flashpoints for conflict and instability (Kalathil 2013). As Manuel Castells (2009) observes, “…there has also been an accentuation of uneven development, this time not only between North and South, but between the dynamic segments and territories of societies everywhere, and those others that risk becoming irrelevant from the perspective of the system's logic” (2). Countries losing out on working-class jobs and who lack strong social safety nets or government investment in jobs, like the U.S., can experience a severe backlash against these developments (Short 2016). At the same time, the emerging network economy, whose linkages between different populations engender and favor socially progressive values like inclusiveness and multiculturalism, has challenged traditional notions of power and privilege in Western nations. The entrance of women into the workforce, and the increasing acceptance and protection of ethnic, racial, and sexual minorities has begun overturning a system in which these groups have traditionally been marginalized (Inglehart and Norris 2016, 7-8).
This is not to say there are no genuine economic grievances involved in this resentment. In fact, the effect of particular ICTs and the globalized economy on certain economic classes in the West has been severe, and may continue as such. In the U.S., manufacturing employment has fallen by almost 40%—that’s about 6 million jobs—since the 1960s. This just represents the net losses—if we look at data specifically from during recessions, we see that factory jobs fell by 10 million (Thompson 2016). One of the most obvious explanations for this trend is the increasing development and adoption of automation—technology that has been programmed to complete physical and cognitive tasks typically assigned to humans. This poses a threat to workers in certain fields—in particular manufacturing, clerical work, retail, and driving—because over time it is cheaper than paying living humans to do the job. It’s been estimated that 47% of jobs are susceptible to automation, which means that while right now the problem primarily affects lower-skilled workers—and, particularly, men—it will soon affect wide swathes of society (The Atlantic 2015).
According to Erik Brynjolfsson and Andrew McAfee (2011), technology is destroying jobs faster than it is creating them, which might explain stagnating median income since the 1970s. These advanced technologies increase productivity, which was previously tied to employment, without actually increasing employment, because humans aren’t needed to produce it. This leads to economic growth and an influx of capital that is not invested back into employees, further exacerbating wealth inequality. Not only is this innovation changing the number of jobs available, but the types of jobs available as well. As computers begin adopting more advanced tasks, replacing traditionally middle-class jobs, there is a polarization of the workforce. Those who have the skills to attain higher-paying jobs (typically those requiring education and computer training) and those who are low-skill whose jobs cannot easily be automated yet (such as janitors or home health aides) will continue to find employment, while the middle class is “hollowed out.”
For other jobs that aren’t or can’t be automated, ICTs and the globalized economy—along with complementary government policies—allow firms to outsource jobs to workers in other countries, where the cost of labor is lower. This generates more wealth for firms, redistributes wealth from high-income to low-income countries, and helps grow the economy overall. But it also increases unemployment in Western countries in which jobs are lost and laborers struggle to re-integrate back into the workforce (Short 2016). Even if these outsourced jobs were, somehow, to be “brought back” to Western countries, they would most likely not be in the form of human employment. To save money, firms would automate as many of these “returning” jobs as possible.
Of course, society has undergone dramatic changes in labor and economic organization in the past, especially since the Industrial Revolution. In 1900, 41% of Americans were employed in agriculture, compared to only 2% in 2000 (Rotman 2013). Clearly, job markets can recover after one industry is wiped out and others pop up. But what happens when a massively disruptive event like the diffusion of advanced ICTs effects not just one industry but many? Best case scenario is that workers adjust their skills to match the requirements of the New Economy, and over time the transition to a network-based economy emphasizes collaborative production and economic inclusiveness. But new models of organization might not play out like that, and even if they do, in the meantime we face significant issues regarding middle- and working-class employment.
In addition, along with global flows of capital has come an increase in immigration, particularly from less-developed countries to the more-developed countries of the West. As ICTs opened up chances for easier travel, laborers moved to areas of greater economic opportunity—usually, developed Western economies. Liberalized policies encouraged this movement of people, as migrants are typically willing to work for lower wages than native populations who expect higher wages and quality of life. This helps firms save on labor and grows the economy, but can also entrench economic inequalities—between those who can make the jump to high-skill, high-wage jobs, and those stuck at the bottom, immigrant and native alike. Whether or not immigration is ever actually as significant, or has quite the consequences, as native populations tend to believe, this remains a flashpoint for potential conflict. This is especially true since immigrants tend to live in major metropolitan areas, which increases their visibility, paired with the aforementioned change in values towards a society that prizes diversity, multiculturalism, and equality (Castells 2009).
IV. The Backlash: The Rise of Right-Wing Populism
Of course, large-scale economic and social phenomena don’t happen in a vacuum. In times of upheaval there are often far-reaching consequences, as systems struggle to adapt and maintain order. Often during these times there is an opening for political movements and leaders who can harness the passions and frustrations of the populace. These impulses are particularly strong among those who perceive themselves to be losing out on prevailing societal trends, compared to others or compared to their prior situations. In Western countries, this has manifested itself in the concurrent ascendance of both left-wing and right-wing populism. The former, exemplified by Occupy Wall Street and the popularity of Bernie Sanders, emphasizes economic equality while using decidedly anti-establishment rhetoric. The latter, exemplified by Donald Trump and the “alt-right,” may hold similar economic views or use the same rhetoric, but with an additional essential focus: nationalism and/or ethno-centrism. Both movements broadly conceive of an “us versus them” narrative, with an established “ruling class” (be it “the media,” “big banks,” “the establishment,” “academia,” “the swamp,” or any such “elites”) pitted against “the people” (Greven 2016).
How one defines “the people” is key. In right-wing populism (RWP), this is usually a narrow definition, limiting the people who deserve to be protected by the government to only those who fit into a pre-determined category. It assumes a culturally homogenous nation of people, often based on ethnicity, race, or religion, who are being oppressed by a ruling class of elites. These elites are said to be favoring an imagined “other” within society—typically racial, ethnic, religious, sexual, or national minorities—at the expense of the “real” members of the nation. Thus the major issue in RWP campaigns tends to be immigration, as immigrants are easily targeted as “others” within the national identity, and scapegoated as economic burdens (whether it’s “taking our jobs” or “taking our benefits.”) (Greven 2016).
The economic changes resulting from the New Economy laid the groundwork for these movements. With the accumulation of wealth within Western societies came an increase in the redistribution of this wealth via social benefits. This inevitably led to conversations about who, exactly, should be allowed to partake in this redistribution. At the same time, growing economic stratification, also led by New Economy technologies and subsequent policies, led to widespread economic grievances. As wealth redistribution had already focused the populace’s attention on matters of national identity, it then became easier to blame immigrants and those who don’t fit this identity for such grievances (Thompson 2016). Add to this the cultural ascendance of minorities and policies that sought to counter historical injustices against them—both products of an emergent progressive value system that challenges entrenched traditional power structures—and you have segments of the population who see their societal “value” advantage diminishing at the hands of “others.” This is where RWP movements step in.
The election of Donald Trump may be the starkest example of rising RWP sentiment in the West, but it is certainly not the only one. Earlier this year the British public’s decision to leave the European Union (Brexit) signaled popular resentment of global, liberal political institutions. While the Brexit vote coalition also included some left-wing populists, the general wave in much of the rest of Europe has been towards RWP. In France, Marine Le Pen and her National Front Party will seek the office of the President in elections next year, emboldened by Trump’s win in the U.S. In Austria, the far-right Norbert Hofer and the Freedom Party lost the most recent presidential election, but still received 46% of the vote (Oltermann 2016). In Germany, Frauke Petry and the Alternative for Germany Party will seek to unseat Angela Merkel next year, who has come to represent global liberalism to many Germans. Other examples include Geert Wilders and the Party for Freedom in the Netherlands, Nigel Farage and the U.K. Independence Party (UKIP) in Britain, and Golden Dawn in Greece. Part of the RWP appeal is the anti-establishment message, which benefits from not actually being in power. But becoming part of “the establishment” may not necessarily even harm these movements’ momentum, as the Law and Justice Party in Poland and Fidesz in Hungary—both currently in power—have proven. Regardless of where these movements are headed, the fact of the matter is that around the Western world, RWP has found a foothold due to a unique set of economic and social changes (Greven 2016).
It’s difficult to untangle the many threads that are relevant when thinking about the motivations of people who are taken in by RWP, as they are varied and intersectional, and the movements themselves can range from simple nationalists to neo-Nazis. This complexity is evident in one of the most visible arguments among Democrats and generally left-leaning people in the month since the American election: the disagreement over whether Donald Trump’s success could best be described by segments of the populace feeling left behind economically (the “economic anxiety” argument) or by his appeal to their explicit or latent racist, sexist, anti-Muslim, or anti-immigrant views (the “bigotry” argument). Of course, this is an inherently false dichotomy—one needn’t be studied in complexity theory to understand that political views, on both an individual and group level, are incredibly complex. It may be impossible to ever really know peoples’ true motivations for voting for Trump, as pre-election opinion polls even failed to recognize his widespread appeal, and the likelihood of voters admitting they voted because of “bigoted” views (whether they regard them as bigoted or not) is fairly low.
But even more importantly, the idea that there is a clear separation between “economic anxiety” and “bigotry” is false. Populist political movements, and particularly those on the right-wing, tend to play the two anxieties, economic and cultural, off each other in a way that blurs the distinction. According to Thomas Greven (2016), Senior Research Fellow of the German Institute for International Relations, Berlin, the central, universal narrative in populist movements is a conception of society in which a corrupt “political class” (alternatively called “elites” or “the establishment”) is oppressing “the people,” defined however the movement sees fit. Populist movements can be left-wing or right-wing, but it is right-wing movements that tend to emphasize that “the people” refers to a very specifically-defined homogeneous group, in opposition to an “other” (typically foreigners or ethnic or religious minorities) (1). The degree to which specific movements highlight particular grievances differs depending on the political context, making it difficult to pin down a movement as explicitly “racist” or bigoted in some way. Some adherents simply despise the political and economic establishment, as evidenced by some of Trump’s and Bernie Sanders’ crossover appeal, while others see immigration and racial justice as a threat to the privilege they’ve enjoyed their whole lives—and there are many layers in between these two.
Linking this back to ICTs, both the “economic anxiety” and “bigotry” explanations for the rise of RWP recognize that the world is changing in significant ways, and fast. ICTs fueled the emergence of globalization, and hastened a transition from an industrial economy to the New Economy, bringing with it a shift to post-materialist values like multiculturalism. They changed the nature of labor in terms of what kind of jobs are available and where they are available. They enabled the kind of quick, easy communication that strengthened the case for global institutions, cross-cultural sharing, and a cosmopolitan worldview. They made known voices that had previously been excluded from public dialogue, empowering those who have been historically ignored—as well as those who want to keep those voices unheard. Regardless of whether you believe the “economic anxiety” argument, the “bigotry” argument, a combination of both, or neither, ICTs have helped create vast structural changes in Western society in a relatively short amount of time, prompting a reactionary movement that has resulted in the rise of RWP. This trend, when placed within the context of the complex global political system, can have serious implications for the current world order.
V. Right-Wing Populism and the Complex International System
The philosopher Karl Popper (2002) once said “…long-term prophecies can be derived from scientific conditional predictions only if they apply to systems which can be described as well-isolated, stationary, and recurrent. These systems are very rare in nature; and modern society is not one of them” (457). The many parts that make up the international system are not particularly isolated, stationary, or recurrent, making the task of projecting big-picture trends into the future rather difficult. The international political system, with its web of alliances, trade agreements, multilateral governance institutions, and other such relationships, most resembles a complex system, and complex systems require specialized analysis. Political scientist Robert Jarvis (1998) said of the complex international system, “we are dealing with a system when a set of units or elements are interconnected so that changes in some elements or their relations produce changes in other parts of the system, and the entirety exhibits properties and behaviours that are different from those other parts” (570). This is particularly true in our modern globalized world, in which an increasing number of actors partake in an increasing number of interactions with other actors, and the nature of these interactions is constantly changing (Cindea 2006).
From a complex systems perspective, human history is “part of the life of the world organism,” as Halford Mackinder (2004), the godfather of geopolitics, noted. The realm of politics does not lie separate from and above all other aspects of human life—rather, it is intertwined with the many conditions that shape our world (Kavalski 2015). This means that changes in economic or social conditions, even relatively minor ones, can have an impact that reverberates throughout the entire system. Placed within the context of the complex international system, the rise of RWP can have a number of consequences on the global order. Perhaps most obviously, RWP movements generally look unfavorably upon free trade agreements and international institutions, preferring unilateralist, protectionist frameworks. Global institutions like NATO and the UN arose from an understanding of complex systems, the goal being to manage the chaos and volatility of an anarchic world by fusing together the interests—whether economic or strategic—of various state actors in a complicated tapestry of interdependence. These agreements rely on a delicate internal balance of power, so that the possibility of an actor reneging on their promises vis-à-vis the group’s purpose increases the likelihood of other actors reneging, and so on at an exponential rate (Newman 2007). The growing popularity of RWP movements threatens the existence of these global institutions, which can act as de facto protections against any number of aggressive inter-state actions. It is possible RWP movements will hasten a rapid breakdown of such institutions, leading to global political instability and, perhaps, a proliferation of conflict.
On the other hand, another aspect of complex systems is that they contain emergent properties, and what may be interpreted as the dissolution of the world order, in the form of crumbling multilateral global agreements and institutions, may actually signal the emergence of a new set of relationships. The tides of globalization that are already underway will continue despite protectionist sentiments, and instead of an “exodus” from the system we may actually see a re-aligning of interests and allegiances. Already, some elements of Western RWP movements have expressed support for Putin’s regime in Russia, breaking with tradition in mainstream conservative factions like the Republican Party in the U.S. This could draw the U.S. into closer relationships with Russia’s partners like Iran and the Assad regime in Syria, signaling a shift away from the Gulf States. This coincides with a RWP preference for domestic as opposed to foreign energy sources, making the U.S. less reliant on the Gulf States for oil, and potentially weakening their alliances. Assuming the Iran nuclear deal holds up—and it may not, given RWP pushback—there’s a chance the U.S. may be closer to Iran than Saudi Arabia in a number of years (DiChristopher 2014). In terms of trade, the hostility towards the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP)—among RWP as well as left-wing populists—means the deal is probably dead. The lack of a U.S. presence opens a political power vacuum regarding economic and environmental regulations that China is eager to fill, allowing them to set the agenda potentially at the expense of the U.S. and its allies (Rosenfeld 2016). In the chaos that ensues from rapid global change, a new set of alliances and institutions may emerge, their nature we can only speculate.
On a more fundamental level, the complex international system can have one of two reactions when exposed to the shock that is the rise of RWP movements: a negative or positive feedback loop. In a negative feedback loop, the rise of RWP movements will trigger opposing reactions once their level of “power” or influence reaches a certain point, challenging their ascendance and re-stabilizing the system. In this conception, the dialectic swung towards RWP, due to a confluence of factors, and the threat posed by RWP to other powerful interests in the system will force the dialectic back the opposite way (Ormand 2016). Possible evidence for this trajectory comes from the fact that far-right Norbert Hofer lost the re-vote for Austrian President by a considerably wider margin than he did the original vote, one potential explanation being the election of Donald Trump between the two votes mobilized voters against Hofer (Oltermann 2016).
On the other hand, in a positive feedback loop, the success of RWP movements can portend the success of other similar groups. In this conception, a contingent of powerful Western democracies “leaving” the liberal international order and erecting protectionist policies may incentivize other countries to do the same (Ormand 2016). Potential evidence for this trajectory is the shocking success of Trump in the American election, which may have gotten a boost from the success of Brexit earlier in the year. There is also evidence that Marine Le Pen of France’s Front National has seen increasing popularity, perhaps emboldened by the growing success of RWP movements in other parts of the West (Kanter 2016).
What happens in either of these cases? Again, the incredible complexity of the international system makes it difficult to predict. As political scientist James N. Rosenau (2006) said, “And so he [the student of world politics] embarks on a search for certainty, only to find that it lies in such phrases as ‘apparently,’ ‘presumably,’ and ‘it would seem as if’” (52). Applying complex systems analysis to the study of international relations may provide a wealth of new, nuanced insights, but it also brings a shade of uncertainty. Its application in the field is also relatively recent, and thus lacks the depth of scholarly attention it will surely receive in the future. As knowledge about complex systems grow, so too will the insights it provides into the study of human interactions as they play out in the field of international relations.
One thing is certain: the rise of RWP movements in the West will have far-reaching consequences around the world. This could take different forms: the ensuing rise of a counter-movement against RWP that brings competing visions of the future into conflict with one another, a global exodus from the international system as nations “tighten” their boundaries at an exponential rate, or the emergence of new alliances and international institutions as old actors leave and new ones enter. In this last case, there could be an “alignment” (of sorts, in a paradoxical way) between anti-globalist RWP-ruled nations on one hand, and between emerging economies like China and their industrializing trade partners in Africa on the other hand. This would mirror the original Western transition to the New Economy, with countries like China and India shifting their production to other, less-developed countries as their economies grew. Perhaps there would even eventually be a similar demographic crisis and subsequent turn towards RWP. Only time will tell, as the many threads underlying the global system play out.
V. Conclusion
RWP came to prominence in Western society within the framework of a complex international system. The rapid growth of ICTs allowed for a level of innovation and disruption that is unprecedented in history. They gave rise to globalized economic and political systems, changing the nature of labor in terms of how we work and where jobs are, and in turn fundamentally altered existing social relations. Subsequently, a backlash against globalization developed within Western countries, taking the form of ascendant RWP movements that synthesized economic and cultural anxieties, particularly among traditionally-advantaged groups who saw these changes as threatening their relative status. It is also within the framework of a complex international system that the rise of RWP will exert influence on other actors and relationships within the system. Regardless of how specifically this will play out, it is likely to cause a significant rift in the global order, and potentially a re-alignment of political interests and alliances.
References
Benkler, Yochai. 2007. The wealth of networks—how social production transforms markets and freedom. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Brynjolffson, Erik, and Andrew McAfee. 2011. Race against the machine: How the digital revolution is accelerating innovation, driving productivity, and irreversibly transforming employment and the economy. Digital Frontier Press.
Castells, Manuel. 2009. The rise of the network society: The information age: Economy, society, and culture, volume I. 2nd ed. Vol. 1. Wiley-Blackwell.
Cindea, Ion. 2006. “Complex Systems—New conceptual tools for international relations.” Perspectives 26.
DiChristopher, Tom. 2014. “US and Iran could have a friendlier future ahead.” CNBC.com2014, sec World Economy.
Freeman, Richard B. 2002. “The labor market in the new information economy.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 18(3), 10.3386/w9254.
Glover, Robert W. “Compatibility or incommensurability: IR theory and complex systems analysis.” In E-International Relations. 2012. Available from http://www.e-ir.info/2012/07/21/compatibility-or-incommensurability-ir-theory-and-complex-systems-analysis/.
Greven, Thomas. 2016. “The rise of right-wing populism in Europe and the United States: A comparative perspective.” Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung (May 2016), http://www.fesdc.org/fileadmin/user_upload/publications/RightwingPopulism.pdf.
Inglehart, Ronald F., and Pippa Norris. 2016. “Trump, Brexit, and the rise of populism: Economic have-nots and cultural backlash.” HKS Working Paper no. RWP16-026, https://ssrn.com/abstract=2818659.
Jervis, Robert. 1998. System effects: Complexity in political and social life. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Kalathil, Shanthi. 2013. “Transparency and volatility: International relations in the information age.” In Diplomacy, development and security in the information age., ed. Shanthi Kalathil, 3-13. Institute for the Study of Diplomacy.
Kanter, Jake. 2016. “France's far-right leader marine le pen thinks Brexit and trump are part of new world order.’ Business Insider, sec Politics.
Kavalski, Emilian. 2015. “Introduction: Inside/Outside and around: Observing the complexity of global life.” In World politics at the edge of chaos., ed. Emilian Kavalski, 1-27. Albany, NY: State University of New York Press.
———. 2007. “The fifth debate and the emergence of complex international relations theory: Notes on the application of complexity theory to the study of international life.” Cambridge Review of International Affairs 20(3), 10.1080/09557570701574154.
Lorenz, Edward N. 1963. “Deterministic nonperiodic flow.” Journal of the Atmospheric Sciences 20, (Jan 7, 1963).
Mackinder, H. J. 2004 (Originally 1904). “The geographical pivot of history.” The Geographical Journal 170(4).
Malik, Mohan. 2012. “Technopolitics: How technology shapes relations among nations.” The Interface of Science, Technology & Security 12.
Newman, Edward. 2007. A crisis of global institutions?: Multilateralism and international security. Global institutions. 1st ed. Routledge.
Oltermann, Philip. 2016. “Austria rejects far-right candidate Norbert Hofer in presidential election.” The Guardian.com, sec Austria.
Ormand, Carol. “What constitutes a complex system?” in Science Education Resource Center (SERC) at Carleton College [database online]. 2016. Available from http://serc.carleton.edu/NAGTWorkshops/complexsystems/introduction.html.
Pohjola, Matti. 2002. “The new economy: Facts, impacts and policies.” Information Economics and Policy 14(2), 10.1016/S0167-6245(01)00063-4.
Popper, Karl. 2002. Conjectures and refutations: The growth of scientific knowledge. 2nd ed. Vol. 17. Routledge.
Powell, Walter W., and Kaisa Snellman. 2004. “The knowledge economy.” Annual Review of Sociology 30, 10.1146/annurev.soc.29.010202.100037.
Rosenau, James N. 2006. The study of world politics, volume 1: Theoretical and methodological challenges. New Edition. Vol. 1. Routledge.
Rosenfeld, Everett. 2016. “Chinese officials are 'licking their lips' at Trump's decision to kill the TPP.” CNBC.com. 2016, sec Trumponomics.
Rotman, David. 2013. “How technology is destroying jobs.” MIT Technology Review (June 12, 2013), https://www.technologyreview.com/s/515926/how-technology-is-destroying-jobs/.
Short, John R. 2016. “Globalization and its discontents: Why there’s a backlash and how it needs to change.” The Conversation.
The Atlantic. 2015. Atlantic interviews: The future of work in America, eds. Derek Thompson, James Bennet. The Atlantic. TheAtlantic.com Video.
Thompson, Derek. 2016. “The next industrial revolution.” The Atlantic.
———. 2016. “When will robots take all the jobs?” The Atlantic.